Wednesday, March 31, 2010

Move Your Money

Move Your Money campaign update:

9% of U.S. adults on board

Move Your Money, the brainchild of Rob Johnson, Arianna Huffington and Eugene Jarecki, has taken America by storm. For anyone who thought grassroots action was futile, think again. According to a recent Zogby poll, nine percent of U.S. adults have taken at least some of their money out of the big banks to protest abuses and bailouts. As we have been reporting, state and local governments are joining the movement. Legislatures in New Mexico and Minnesota inspired by the campaign have proposed measures that would prioritize local banks for dealing with state deposits.

John Zogby in Forbes:

We know that people are mad as hell about their tax dollars going to bail out big banks and Wall Street, and then seeing the recipients of their hard-earned cash rewarding themselves with million-dollar bonuses.
We also know that the blowback from the bank bailouts is one reason why incumbents, especially the majority Democrats, are in great jeopardy of losing their jobs in November. People can’t vote out big bankers, but we are finding evidence that some people are voting with their bank accounts and moving their business to community banks and credit unions. A recent Zogby Interactive poll found 9% of U.S. adults have taken some of their business away from big banks as a protest.
The MYM site has a tool that lets you enter your zipcode and find a highly-rated community bank near you.


Tuesday, March 30, 2010

Major Victory for Education in America

3 Cheers for the New Student Lending Law

*Update, 12:39 p.m., Obama signed the bill into law.

Today President Obama signed a bill that overhauls of the student loan industry.* For decades, the federal government has supported student lenders by backing loans originated by private banks. Today we take back the bank subsidy and use it to spend down the deficit and pay low-income kids to finish college. Good day.

Our byzantine student lending system is essentially the product of two competing principles: managed affordability and capitalism. The government guarantees the loans because otherwise private banks wouldn't make low-rate loans to an 18-year old kid with no earnings, no credit history, and zero collateral when he won't start paying interest in four years. So the banks get the interest and the government gets stuck with 97% of the losses if the student defaults. Heads, students pay the bank. Tails, taxpayers pay the bank.

But the government has been loathe to take over the industry itself -- even if it means leaving tens of billions of dollars on the table -- because reasonable efforts to simplify the system are met with hysterical screaming about socialism from former Education secretaries who should really know better.

Effective today, student lending will be a government-run program. What does that mean for borrowing students? Not a whole lot, as I understand it. They will fill out the same paperwork and pay similar interest rates. They'll even see annual payments capped at 10 percent of current income. The only difference is that their interest -- roughly $7 billion a year for the next decade -- will go to the feds instead of the banks. The government plans to set some of that money aside for deficit reduction, inject billions into Pell grants for low-income students and channel some of it into education initiatives like community college support.

The opponents from the private student lending industry are right: they will lose some jobs. But not all jobs. Private lenders will still complete paperwork and administer the loans. All things equal, I'd prefer this policy go into effect when unemployment wasn't clinging to double digits. But I support the change wholeheartedly. And as the New America Foundation's Jason Delisle told me, these private lenders don't particularly deserve my tears: "under the pretext of competition and choice and the private sector is a smokescreen for banks who want to highjack this federal student loan program and sell kids credit card like loans when they're least likely to know what they're getting into. Really, these are the jobs we want to protect?"

 http://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2010/03/3-cheers-for-the-new-student-lending-law/38188/

Sunday, March 28, 2010

U.S. Unemployment


Follow the change in unemployment from the beginning of the current recession. Below, the state-by-state unemployment rate from the Bureau of Labor Statistics, seasonally adjusted. Updated: 3/26/2010


An Extended Excerpt from todays' Guardian


Steve Eisman: Maverick Trader

The financial crisis was predictable, but only a handful saw it coming. Of those, even fewer were bold enough to bet against the market. And the boldest of them all was an unknown trader

"He agreed, though: the main effect was to transfer the financial risk to the shareholders."

"When things go wrong, it's their problem," he said – and obviously not theirs alone. When the Wall Street investment bank screwed up badly enough, its risks became the problem of the US government. "It's laissez-faire until you get in deep shit," he said, with a half chuckle. He was out of the game. It was now all someone else's fault."


 http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2010/mar/20/steve-eisman-maverick-trader-financial-crisis

Saturday, March 27, 2010

Unemployment Heat Map - Monthly since 1948

U.S. Unemployment ~ A Historical View compliments of WSJ

Track the national unemployment rate since 1948 -- the first year in which the government provides data that can reliably be compared with the current rate. Numbers are seasonally adjusted. Updated: 03/05/2010

 

Tuesday, March 23, 2010

Lehman Post Mortem framed in an intriguing literary context

"The 2,200-page bank examiner’s autopsy released 10 days ago concluded that Lehman, in league with its auditor Ernst & Young, used “materially misleading” accounting gimmicks to mask its losses, duping investors and the ever-credulous Securities and Exchange Commission alike." (but apparently not criminal)

Op-Ed Columnist

Obama, Lehman and ‘The Dragon Tattoo’

By FRANK RICH Published: March 20, 2010
 
 
THE same week that Lehman Brothers collapsed in September 2008, a Swedish crime novel titled “The Girl With the Dragon Tattoo” was published in America. The book didn’t receive a ton of hype, not least because the author, a journalist named Stieg Larsson, was unavailable for interviews; he had died in 2004 of a heart attack at the age of 50. The mixed Times review appeared in the back pages of the Sunday Book Review. Many more readers were riveted instead by the Lehman article on that morning’s front page: “A Wall Street Goliath Teeters Amid Fears of a Widening Crisis.” 
 
excerpt:
 
“A bank director who blows millions on foolhardy speculations should not keep his job,” writes Larsson in one typical passage. “A managing director who plays shell company games should do time.” Larsson is no less lacerating about influential journalists who treat “mediocre financial whelps like rock stars” and who docilely “regurgitate the statements issued by C.E.O.’s and stock-market speculators.” He pleads for some “tough reporter” to “identify and expose as traitors” the financial players who have “systematically and perhaps deliberately” damaged their country’s economy “to satisfy the profit interests of their clients.” 

Perspective

 
March 23, 2010, 1:37 pm

Deepening Deficits, Around the Developed World

The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development has put together a handy set of numbers showing deficits around the developed world. And according to the O.E.C.D., every developed country except Norway ran a deficit last year:


Regulatory Reform in the context of financial stability and competition implications

Bailing out the Banks: Reconciling Stability and Competition

An analysis of state-supported schemes for financial institutions

Thorsten Beck, Diane Coyle, Mathias Dewatripont, Xavier Freixas and Paul Seabright


The financial crisis of 2008 has seen the fall of several of the mighty US investment banks, the collapse of renowned commercial banks on both sides of the Atlantic and the exhaustion of banks' capital all over the world. With it, standard views of banks, financial markets, their risks and their regulation had to be suspended, at a time when bank bailouts became unavoidable. This raises key policy questions on the way taxpayers' resources should be used: What type of capital should governments inject? How should banks' shareholders and creditors be treated? Does capital injection distort competition? Should the standard rules preventing anti-competitive behaviour be applied? How to contain future risk-taking by banks?


This report assesses two related aspects of the policy response to the unprecedented financial crisis: competition policy and financial regulation. It addresses both the effectiveness of the response to the current crisis, and the lessons that can be drawn in order to reduce the likelihood of future crises.


The links between competition policy and banking stability are central to assessing the crisis policy response, and in particular the effectiveness of state aid control. There have been two contrasting views of the relationship between competition and stability - one is that stability is such an urgent issue in the crisis context that it overrides competition concerns, while the alternative view is that intervention to restore financial stability will lead to massive distortions of competition in the banking sector, and so competition rules should be applied even more vigorously than usual.


In contrast to these two views, this report concludes that competition policy is indeed more important than ever in times of crisis, but that the competition rules appropriate to the banking sector are different from those that apply in other sectors. This is because bailing out one bank in an episode of crisis helps its competitors, and state aid rules should reflect this characteristic. Additionally, while European competition authorities have tried, since the autumn of 2008, to strike the appropriate balance between the insistence on competition concerns and the need for urgent action to respond to the financial crisis, the time has now come for a thorough competitive assessment of the banking sector following the recent bailouts. The fact that aid to individual banks has sector-wide competition implications means that a competition assessment conducted on a case-by-case basis is not sufficient.



The report also makes a series of recommendations about regulatory reform, with regard to both financial stability and competition implications. Critically, the report calls for a strengthening of competences at the European level, beyond coordination mechanisms.


Download the report here [PDF 408 KB]




Mining the Archives of VoxEU.org reveals more of Who saw it coming and How

'No one saw this coming' – or did they?

Dirk Bezemer
30 September 2009


Did economists not see this crisis coming? This column says that analysts who used models featuring a distinct financial sector issued fairly detailed, well reasoned, and public warnings of imminent finance turmoil. It argues that mainstream models missed the crisis because they use a “reflective finance” view in which financial variables are wholly determined by the real sector. “Flow of funds” models may be the way forward for anticipating finance-induced recessions.

From the very beginning of the credit crisis and the ensuing recession, it has become conventional wisdom that "no one saw this coming". Anatole Kaletsky (2008) wrote in the The Times of “those who failed to foresee the gravity of this crisis - a group that includes Mr King, Mr Brown, Alistair Darling, Alan Greenspan and almost every leading economist and financier in the world.” Glenn Stevens (2008), Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia, said:
“I do not know anyone who predicted this course of events. This should give us cause to reflect on how hard a job it is to make genuinely useful forecasts. What we have seen is truly a ‘tail’ outcome – the kind of outcome that the routine forecasting process never predicts. But it has occurred, it has implications, and so we must reflect on it”.
We must indeed.

What now for economic modeling?

One result from such reflection would be that in fact, many had predicted this course of events for years. In a recent study (Bezemer 2009), I document the economists who did “see it coming”. At least a dozen serious analysts issued fairly detailed, well reasoned, and public warnings of imminent finance-induced recession.
They were apparently ignored by Stevens and other central bankers who then, as Alan Greenspan professed in his October 2008 testimony, watched with “shocked disbelief” as their “whole intellectual edifice collapse in the summer [of 2007]”. The official models they relied on missed the crisis not because the conditions were so unusual, as we are often told. They missed it by design.
It is impossible to warn against a debt deflation recession in a model world where debt does not exist. This is the world in which our policymakers have been living, and they urgently need to change habitat. The question that the economics profession now needs to address is – whereto? If our routine forecasting models – CGE models, mostly – failed to foresee this, where do we look for alternatives?

The types of models that got it right

In Bezemer (2009), I document the models that got it right. The important question for economists is – how did they do it? What is the underlying model?
While there is obviously a diversity of approaches, one important strand of thinking is an accounting of financial stocks (debt and wealth) and flows (of credit, interest, profit and wages), as well as explicit analysis of both the real economy and the financial sector (including property).
The most detailed of these models, which has also been used to construct public projections and analyses, are “Flow of Funds” models of the US developed by Wynne Godley and associates at the Levy Economics Institute. These may serve as pars pro toto for the class of “Flow of Funds” models of real-financial interactions (e.g. also Werner, 1997; Graziani, 2003; Hudson, 2006; Keen, 2009). A simplified (closed-economy) representation in Godley (1999) consists of stocks and flows of a number of asset classes between four sectors (explicitly separating out the financial sector), with their properties and interrelations represented in over 60 equations (Table 1; see Godley 1999 for all symbols).

Table 1. The flow of funds in matrix representation

Source: Godley (1999:395)

Flow of funds models

In “Flow of Funds” models, liquidity generated in the financial sector flows to firms, households and the government as they borrow. This may facilitate fixed-capital investment and production, but it may also feed asset price inflation, consumption, and debt growth. Liquidity returns to the financial sector as financial investments or in payment of debt service and financial fees. Key features of “Flow of Funds” models are thus bank credit flows, since “evolving finance in the form of bank loans is required if production is to be financed …” (Godley, 1999:405). Also, there are explicit payment flows such as interest, “not quite the same as in the national accounts, where it is standard practice… to ignore interest payments, although they are an inevitable cost given that production takes time” (Godley, 1999:405).
The model is solved by imposing macro accounting identities and adaptive expectations rather than individual optimisation. There is a steady state but not equilibrium. One advantage is that growth paths can be identified as unsustainable given the existing “bedrock” accounting relations. This allowed Godley and Wray in 2000 to conclude that “Goldilocks was doomed” – with a government surplus and current account deficit, US economic growth had to be predicated on ongoing and unsustainably high rates of private debt growth.

What’s missing from the mainstream models?

This inference is impossible to make from national or OECD forecasters’ models, where balance sheet variables or interest flows are conspicuous by their absence. These CGE models do not include a separate financial sector, ruling out finance-induced recession by design. Money supply and interest rate variables are included in those models, but they are fully determined by real-sector variables such as the output gap. Also, the process of money stock growth or asset market inflation – by bank lending which increases debt levels and elicits return flows of interest – are not modelled. This fits in with a “reflective finance” view; the financial sector, rather than developing its own dynamic, is assumed to adapt to the “real fundamentals”, so that explicitly modelling it is superfluous.
The contrast with actually existing finance-induced recessions should lead forecasters to reconsider their models. Interestingly, there have been moves in recent years towards including balance sheets and the flow of funds in official models. Rae and Turner (2001) write that introducing “alternative assumptions allows a little more economic richness to be temporarily added to the [OECD Small Global Forecasting] model when it is used for policy analyses, especially for those situations in which financial markets and expectations play important roles in the transmission of shocks within and between regions”. In addition to its ad hoc adjustment to the reality of balance sheet effects, the OECD appears to be working on a new “Interlink” model, triggered by “changing conditions” and including “domestic and global stock-flow consistency with respect to wealth linkages and wealth effects” (Richardson 2006), very similar in name at least to Godley’s “stock-flow consistent model” (Godley and Lavoie 2006).
So far, however, monetary (and other) policymakers have resisted inclusion of balance sheets and the flow of funds in their models and policy responses. Greenspan famously preferred to “mitigate the fallout when it occurs and, hopefully, ease the transition to the next expansion”. But the underestimation of the severity of the fallout (global recession) throws the desirability of the transition to the next expansion into doubt if it is to be driven by debt accumulation. Also, the argument that bubbles cannot be timely identified nor their effects reliably anticipated is rebutted by the analysts reviewed in my paper who did both.

Conclusions

While the jury is still out on the question whether CGE models and “Flow of Funds” models can be married, exploring these avenues is now urgent. Benjamin Friedman recently noted that, “what is sorely missing in the discussion is attention to what function the financial system is supposed to perform in the economy and how well it has been doing it”. “Flow of Funds” models provide just that. If the crisis and recession teach us one thing, it is that the financial sector is just as real as the “real economy”. We economists – and the policymakers who rely on us – ignore balance sheets and the flow of funds at our peril.
Editor’s note: The author’s short Comment on this topic was published by the Financial Times on 8 September 2009.

References

Bezemer, Dirk J (2009), “No One Saw This Coming”: Understanding Financial Crisis Through Accounting Models. Unpublished.
CPB (2009), “Central Economic Plan 2009” (in Dutch). The Hague: Centraal Planbureau.
Friedman, B (2009), “The Failure Of The Economy And The Economists”. New York Review of Books, LVI (9): 42–45, 28 May.
Godley, W (1999), “Money and Credit in a Keynesian Model of Income Determination”, Cambridge Journal of Economics 23(4): pp. 393-411.
Godley, W and M Lavoie (2006), Monetary Economics: An Integrated Approach to Credit, Money, Income, Production and Wealth. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire UK Palgrave-Macmillan.
Godley, W and R Wray (2000), “Is Goldilocks Doomed?”, Journal of Economic Issues 34: 201-206.
Graziani, A (2003), The Monetary Theory Of Production. Federico Caffe Lectures. Cambridge; New York and Melbourne: Cambridge University Press.
Greenspan, A (2008), “Testimony for the Committee of Government Oversight and Reform”, 23 October.
Hudson, M. (2006), “Saving, Asset-Price Inflation, and Debt-Induced Deflation”, in L. Randall Wray and Matthew Forstater, eds., Money, Financial Instability and Stabilization Policy Edward Elgar, 2006:104-24.
Kaletsky, A (2008), “It’s An Emergency. Long-Term Cures Must Wait”, The Times, 13 November.
Keen, S (2009), “The Dynamics Of The Monetary Circuit”, in Jean-François Ponsot and Sergio Rossi (eds.), The Political Economy of Monetary Circuits: Tradition and Change. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire UK: Palgrave, London
Rae, D and D Turner (2001), “A Small Global Forecasting Model”, Working Paper 286, OECD Economics Department.
Reuters (2007) “US Recession Risk Still Below 50 Pct”. 5 September.
Richardson, P (2006) “The Structure And Simulation Properties Of OECD’s Interlink Model”.
Stevens, G. (2008), Speech to the Australian Business Economists, December 9.
Werner, R (1997), “Towards a New Monetary Paradigm: A Quantity Theorem of Disaggregated Credit, with Evidence from Japan”. Kredit und Kapital, 30,2. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot., 276-309.

This article may be reproduced with appropriate attribution. See Copyright (below).

Monday, March 22, 2010

John Lounsbury of Seeking Alpha debunking the myth that "No One Saw this Coming!" and how those that could, did...


'...the elements in the economy that are at the root cause of the current crisis are absent from the models of economic activity that are used to guide economic policy. The entire financial sector is absent. The very elements that have siphoned the life blood out of the economy have been completely off the radar screen. The FIRE was hidden behind a shield of invisibility, just pumping money into their coffers until the real economy bled out."

No One Saw This Economic Crisis Coming?



A research paper, published in June by Dirk J. Bezemer, Groningen University, addresses this question and says the answer is that many saw it coming but those with the power to act did nothing. Bezemer contends that the problem is that economic policy is executed using macro equilibrium models and what is needed to establish economic policy that can anticipate crises, such as we have now, and take actions to head them off, are micro accounting cash-flow models. The entire paper can be read here.

and John Lounsbury's analysis here. 

Anticipations of the Housing Crisis and the Recession


The Seers - Click Tables to Enlarge

Michael Lewis Podcast on KQED Forum

Mon, Mar 22, 2010 -- 10:00 AM

Michael Lewis on the Financial Crisis
 
Berkeley-based author Michael Lewis joins us to discuss his latest book, "The Big Short: Inside the Doomsday Machine." Lewis' other books include "The Blind Side," "Moneyball," "Liar's Poker" and "Home Game: An Accidental Guide to Fatherhood."


Part 1 - Inside the Collapse 60 Minutes with Michael Lewis


Watch CBS News Videos Online

Part 2 - Inside the Collapse 60 Minutes with Michael Lewis


Watch CBS News Videos Online

Sunday, March 21, 2010

Real Clear Politics Poll

Job Approval Approve Disapprove Spread
Obama 47.2% 47.8% -0.6%
Congress 19.0% 75.8% -56.8%

Country Direction

Right

Wrong

Spread
RCP Average 33.8% 60.5% -26.7%

Saturday, March 20, 2010

by 2050 nothing but the Big 3... Social Security, Medicare and Medicaid

The Future of the Deficit

The Heritage Foundation has put together some good historical numbers on the kinds of spending that the federal government does. Those numbers appear alongside my column this week.

If you want to get a sense for where spending is headed, have a look at this chart from the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities:


http://economix.blogs.nytimes.com/2010/03/16/the-future-of-the-deficit/?ref=economy

The Fiscal Sustainability Conundrum... a return to PayGo?

Economic Scene

The Perils of Pay Less, Get More




"In 1900, federal taxes amounted to just 2 percent of gross domestic product. By 2000, the share had risen to 21 percent.


Over the last couple of decades, though, we have repealed Wagner’s Law — or, more to the point, only partly repealed it. Taxes are no longer rising. They fell to 18 percent of G.D.P. in 2008 and, because of the recession, to a 60-year low of 15.1 percent last year.


Yet our desire for government services just keeps growing. We added a prescription drug benefit to Medicare. Farm subsidies are sacrosanct. Social Security is the third rail of politics,"

http://www.nytimes.com/2010/03/17/business/economy/17leonhardt.html?adxnnl=1&ref=economy&adxnnlx=1269111870-fWWg/DxTzmw2BNJ8OhTSvQ

Economic Indicators - Scroll Through Snapshot




Thursday, March 18, 2010

Buy this Book! Oh ...and Read it.



Econned: How Unenlightened Self Interest Undermined Democracy and Corrupted Capitalism
released March 2, 2010

I thought the extract below would give readers an idea of what the book is about, with one caveat. Econned goes into some detail about crisis mechanisms (as in why it got as bad as it did) and has unearthed a heretofore unexamined hedge fund trading strategy that turned the subprime mania into the detonator of the global debt bomb (and yes, we have the goods).

Enjoy!

In 1776, Adam Smith published The Wealth of Nations. In it, he argued that the uncoordinated actions of large numbers of individuals, each acting out of self-interest, sometimes produced, as if by “an invisible hand,” results that were beneficial to broader society. Smith also pointed out that self-interested actions frequently led to injustice or even ruin. He fiercely criticized both how employers colluded with each other to keep wages low, as well as the “savage injustice” that European mercantilist interests had “commit[ted] with impunity” in colonies in Asia and the Americas.

Smith’s ideas were cherry-picked and turned into a simplistic ideology that now dominates university economics departments. This theory proclaims that the “invisible hand” ensures that economic self-interest will always lead to the best outcomes imaginable. It follows that any restrictions on the profit-seeking activities of individuals and corporations interfere with this invisible hand, and therefore are “inefficient” and nonsensical.

According to this line of thinking, individuals have perfect knowledge both of what they want and of everything happening in the world at large, and so they pass their lives making intelligent decisions. Prices may change in ways that appear random, but this randomness follows predictable, unchanging rules and is never violently chaotic. It is therefore possible for corporations to use clever techniques and systems to reduce or even eliminate the risks associated with their business. The result is a stable, productive economy that represents the apex of civilization.

This heartwarming picture airbrushes out nearly all of the real business world. Yet uncritical allegiance to these precepts over the last thirty years has produced a world in which corporations, especially in finance, are far less restricted in their pursuit of profit. We show in this book how this lawless environment has led the financial services industry to pursue its own unenlightened
self-interest. The industry has become systematically predatory. Employees of industry firms have not confined their predation to outsiders; their efforts to loot their own firms nearly destroyed the industry and the entire global economy. Similarly destructive behavior by other players, often viewed through a distorted lens that saw all unconstrained commercial behavior as virtuous, added more
fuel to the conflagration.

Some economists have opposed this prevailing ideology; indeed, comparatively new lines of inquiry focus explicitly on how economic actors can fool themselves or others into making poor, even destructive, choices.

But when the economics profession has used the megaphone of its authority to dominate discussions with policymakers and the public, it has spoken with one voice, and the message has been the one described here. We therefore confine our criticism to these particularly influential ideas.

Theories that fly in the face of reality often need to excise inconvenient phenomena, and mainstream economics is no exception. Idealizing the rational aspects of business decisions means refusing to notice behavior that is predatory, destructive, criminal, or simply stupid. Believing that risk is manageable through mechanical systems has required not just unrealistic assumptions but also willful
blindness to clear signs of danger.

We offer here another point of view. This book lays bare both the actions leading to the credit crisis and the economic constructs that defended, facilitated, and even exacerbated this behavior. Our case makes clear that if our economic system is to harness the self-interest of individuals to achieve the general good, it must be supervised within a democratic society and responsive to criticism by outside voices of those who are unafraid to think independently.


Yves Smith of www.nakedcapitalism.com fame. 


Voices of Reason

Feminomics: Top Five Heroes of Financial Reform

1) Yves Smith Naked Capitalism

 

2) Elizabeth Warren  Congressional Oversight Panel

 

3) Meredith Whitney "The Rise and Rise of Analyst Meredith Whitney"

 

4) Gretchen Morgenson New York Times Business Columnist

 

5) Sheila Bair Head of the FDIC "Bair Cautions Banking Crisis Is Not Over"

 

http://www.huffingtonpost.com/joe-costello/feminomics-top-five-heroe_b_407351.html

Financial Treason ...and a more consumer friendly perspective

Yesterday, the ABA's top lobbyist, Ed Yingling, said that every week that passes gives the Republicans more leverage. The Republicans could gum up the bill once it hits the floor, delaying financial reform altogether.

"Another thing to understand is the clock is very important here," Yingling said. "It's March. The Congress probably has only 60 more days before they really get into the total election season -- 60 more work days."

Top GOP Senator, Richard Shelby (Alabama): 

"We're Willing To Wait Out The Clock On Wall Street Reform"

Shelby wowed the crowd of bankers assembled at the ABA summit, receiving several rounds of applause and a standing ovation at the conclusion of a speech in which he assailed Dodd's bill and re-asserted his belief that the banking sector's profitability is more important than consumer protection.

"Safety and soundness trumps everything," Shelby said to loud applause. "It trumps the consumer finance whatever."

Shelby's point was that if banks aren't profitable, then they won't be in a position to lend.

He then told the crowd that if they wanted to kill the proposed consumer agency, which would protect borrowers from predatory lenders, they should "elect more Republicans to the U.S. Senate."

in the pursuit of balance... Here's another perspective...

Payback Time

Corporate Debt Coming Due May Squeeze Credit



The New York Times
http://www.nytimes.com/2010/03/16/business/16debt.html


The Crash of 1929 - PBS




Did you know? Viewers like you are our largest single source of support.


Wednesday, March 17, 2010

Move Your Money... remember diversification risk...

Where Big Banks Rule (and Where They Don't)


The New York Times has a nice graphic showing which parts of the country favor small banks and which favor large banks. Any bank with more than $65 billion in assets counts as "large" here, and that includes most of the national banks you've heard of: Citigroup, Bank of America, JP Morgan Chase, Wachovia, and Wells Fargo, among others.

Why is this relevant? Well, big banks take more of your money in fees, and tend to take bigger risks. There's a campaign underway called Move Your Money that has more information and tips if you want to make the switch to a smaller bank.

"Simply terrific. Easily the best of the post-crash financial books." --Malcolm Gladwell

Apparently Zuckerman's Book is the definitive account of the contrarians who bet against Wall Street and won:



Michael Lewis on "the seers who see 'debt' people" interview on Fresh Air with Terry Gross on NPR

"Everybody [on Wall Street] was working with the same set of facts about subprime mortgage lending — about how subprime mortgage loans were turned into bonds and repackaged and turned into CDOs and so on and so forth," Lewis tells Terry Gross. "[And] the vast majority of the people in the markets took those facts and painted one kind of picture with it; it was a very pleasant picture. And a very small handful of people took the same facts and painted a completely different kind of picture with it. [I wanted to find out] 'What is it that enables [the people who bet against the market] to paint that picture?' and 'Why do these people look at the world differently?' "





The Big Short: Inside the Doomsday Machine
By Michael Lewis
Hardcover, 288 pages
W. W. Norton & Co.
List price: $27.95

Tuesday, March 16, 2010

Brilliant clarification of Lehman's REPO 105 by Paddy Hirsch, very Khanesque



Repo 105 from Marketplace on Vimeo.

&

The Origins of Lehman’s ‘Repo 105’

March 12, 2010, 7:02 am



"It’s not clear that there was a crime committed in the fall of Lehman Brothers. But the court-appointed examiner’s report makes it clear that there was financial massaging going on.

The examiner, Anton R. Valukas, refers repeatedly to “Repo 105,” a name for a set of accounting tactics originated by Lehman that temporarily shuffled about $50 billion off the firm’s balance sheet for the two fiscal quarters before it collapsed."

Monday, March 15, 2010

New American Bank Initiative: 

Removing Structural Flaws in the Economic Rescue

Sal Khan has co-authored with Berkeley professor Dr. David Leibweber a possible solution to unfreezing the credit markets...

View in html
Download PDF
Watch CNN Segment

A Structural Approach to Economic Recovery- The US economic rescue effort has seen our government charge up one hill after another, only to charge back down again. The inherent design flaws in these approaches reflect a need for coherent systems thinking to make technological, and financial systems work properly. This proposal, for a New American Banking Initiative, seeks to apply those ideas to help in our current crisis.

Please feel free to join the discussion of this topic here

Also view the discussion at O'Reilly Radar

Superheroes Rescue Plan "Out of this World!" (Part I)

 http://www.monkeybusinessblog.com/goldman_superheroes/2008/09/superheroes-res.html

Superheroes Rescue Plan "Out of this World!" (Part II)

 http://www.monkeybusinessblog.com/goldman_superheroes/2008/09/superheroes-r-1.html

Superheroes Rescue Plan "Out of this World!" (Part III)


Sunday, March 14, 2010

Indiana Jones for the 21st Century... is this for real or just a typo? I'll hope for the latter.

from Harvey Organ:
Rob Kirby with a fascinating find:
Subject: looky here

Go to the Fed's "flow of funds report" Q4/09 just released today at this link:


Scroll down to page 24 [Flow of Funds with Rest of World] and observe line # 14 on that page. It states that the U.S. Fed sold 190.7 billion dollars worth of gold / SDRs in Q3/09. 190.7 billion @ 1,000 per ounce would be 5,937 tonnes of gold .

A Chartered Financial Analyst subscriber of mine follows this release every quarter and alerted me to the "back-dating" of the gold sales for Q3/09 in the release today. Note: In the same flow of funds report for Q3/09 at this appended link - there was no mention of gold / SDR sales - period:


I've attached the Flow of Funds Report for both Q3/09 and Q4/09 for comparison purposes.

Question: has the Federal Reserve just "papered over" the disgorgement of nearly 6,000 metric tonnes of sovereign U.S. Gold bullion?

best,
Rob Kirby
end.

The report is from the federal reserve government releases and it shows the flow of funds in the 4th quarter.

I checked the government data and sure enough on page 24, line 14 the usa sold 190.7 billion dollars of gold (SDR's translated into real oz). At 1000 dollars per oz that translates into 5937 tonnes of gold.

The previous quarter on the flow of funds reports showed no gold activity. Looks like the usa is trying to paper over their sale of 6000 metric tonnes of gold.

The usa has 8133 tonnes of gold so 73% of the usa gold reserves have been liquidated.

The problem here is that the gold belongs to its citizens and not government. The government needs congressional approval to sell the gold.

Trouble ahead on this front!

Remember, remember....

It’s Déjà Voodoo Economics... All Over Again

By: Eric Sprott & David Franklin

If you’re of a certain age, chances are you remember exactly where you were when JFK was  assassinated. Similarly, if you’re from Canada or the United States and have an even remote interest  in hockey, it’s highly likely that you remember exactly where you were when ‘Sid the Kid’ scored the  winning overtime goal in the Olympic gold medal game. These were both "significant events", albeit  for different reasons. We wonder, however, if any of you recall where you were on September 18th,  2008? Do you remember that day? We can’t seem to recall it either, which is strange, because it was  one of the most important days of the decade. October 7, 2008 is another day that should stick out  in our memories, but we’re sure you don’t remember that day either – and we’re in the same boat.  How is it, then, that we can’t recall where we were or what we were doing on the two days the entire  financial system almost collapsed?!? It boggles our mind. These dates should have been emphasized  in every "review of the decade" written at the end of 2009, but we’ve been hard pressed to find them  mentioned in any mainstream publication. This is troubling to us, and makes us wonder if people are  even aware of the incredible events that took place on those fateful days only eighteen months ago...

Saturday, March 13, 2010

Mirrored, all 21st Century Job Growth Erased.

The Conclusion of the Great Shedding?

Chart: Payroll employment in January 2010




Total non-farm payroll employment was essentially unchanged in January (-20,000), according to the U.S. Department of Labor's Bureau of Labor Statistics. The change in total non-farm payroll employment for November 2009 was revised from 4,000 to 64,000, and the change for December 2009 was revised from -85,000 to -150,000.


Construction employment declined by 75,000 in January, with non-residential specialty trade contractors (-48,000) accounting for the majority of the decline. Since December 2007, employment in construction has fallen by 1.9 million.

In January, transportation and warehousing employment fell by 19,000, due to a large job loss among couriers and messengers (-23,000).

Temporary help services added 52,000 jobs in January. Since reaching a low point in September 2009, temporary help services employment has risen by 247,000.

This employment data is from the Current Employment Statistics program and is seasonally adjusted. Data for the most recent two months is preliminary. Monthly revisions result from additional sample reports and the monthly recalculation of seasonal factors. The annual benchmark process also contributed to these revisions. To learn more, see "The Employment Situation — January 2010" (HTML) (PDF), news release USDL-10-0141.

Thursday, March 11, 2010

New Deal 2.0

Another Crisis on the Way? Rob Johnson on C-Span

Thursday, 03/11/2010 - 2:12 pm by Lynn Parramore | Post a Comment
 
Today on C-Span, Robert Johnson, Director of the Project on Global Finance at the Roosevelt Institute, reviews necessary financial reforms outlined in the recently-released Make Markets Be Markets report. Johnson warns that another crisis is on the way unless we get serious about reform. He warns that deceptive accounting practices, complexity, excessive leverage, regulatory capture, and no system to handle too big to fail institutions still pose a giant threat to our economy.

On the spirit that informs the work of the Roosevelt Institute, Johnson describes FDR as “a man who was extremely forthright and courageous at a time of great transition.”

On the current administration’s reform efforts: “I don’t see a human system, I don’t see the political will, I don’t see the President of the United States leading the charge.”

Taking questions from callers, Johnson discusses the dark side of Citigroup, the European Union, hedge funds, derivatives, Gary Gensler, consumer financial protection, and the regulatory proposals on the table in Washington.

Watch the interview here.

Wednesday, March 10, 2010

The Crisis in Historical Context & Why The $ Won't Collapse

Putting crisis in context
 

In a fascinating paper to the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, Yale economist Gary Gorton puts the crisis in the context of a long history of bank runs, with 21st-century wrinkles. And at Project Syndicate, Harvard economist Martin Feldstein throws cold water on arguments that the dollar is due for a collapse.



Economic Indicators - Scroll Through Snapshot

Economic Indicators





Diproportional US Subsidies vs. US Recommended Daily Allowance

March 9, 2010, 11:56 am

Why a Big Mac Costs Less Than a Salad



Minimum Wage Increase may have converted Full Time to Part Time?

March 10, 2010, 7:22 am

Did the Minimum Wage Increase Destroy Jobs?

meanwhile at the Commodity Futures Trading Commission...

CFTC Chief Calls for New Credit-Derivatives Rules

"Mr. Gensler's comments, to be made in a speech later Tuesday at a New York conference held by Markit, come as the European Union's executive arm threatened to ban some credit default swaps in a swipe at speculators who made huge bets against the euro amid Greece's debt crisis."

"His speech outlined several options for reining in credit-default swaps. But Mr. Gensler didn't suggest that the U.S. would go as far as banning some speculative uses of the products."

http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704784904575112060918501130.html?mod=WSJ_hpp_MIDDLETopStories 

 interesting to note the inception date? 

Begs the Question of just how Effective this Commission is?